Coe hess global networks.pdf

(305 KB) Pobierz
‘Globalizing’ regional development: a
global production networks perspective
Blackwell Publishing, Ltd.
Neil M Coe*, Martin Hess*, Henry Wai-chung Yeung†,
Peter Dicken* and Jeffrey Henderson‡
Recent literature concerning regional development has placed significant emphasis on
local institutional structures and their capacity to ‘hold down’ the global. Conversely,
work on inter-firm networks – such as the global commodity chain approach – has
highlighted the significance of the organizational structures of global firms’ production
systems and their relation to industrial upgrading. In this paper, drawing upon a
global production networks perspective, we conceptualize the connections between
‘globalizing’ processes, as embodied in the production networks of transnational
corporations, and regional development in specific territorial formations. We delimit
the ‘strategic coupling’ of the global production networks of firms and regional
economies which ultimately drives regional development through the processes of
value creation, enhancement and capture. In doing so, we stress the multi-scalarity of
the forces and processes underlying regional development, and thus do not privilege
one particular geographical scale. By way of illustration, we introduce an example
drawn from recent research into global production networks in East Asia and Europe.
The example profiles the investments of car manufacturer BMW in Eastern Bavaria,
Germany and Rayong, Thailand, and considers their implications for regional
development.
key words
globalization
global production networks
regional development
Asia
Europe
*School of Environment and Development, University of Manchester, Oxford Road, Manchester M13 9PL
email: neil.coe@manchester.ac.uk
†Department of Geography, National University of Singapore
‡Manchester Business School, and the School of Environment and Development, University of Manchester
revised manuscript received 10 May 2004
emphasis on endogenous institutional structures
and their capacity to ‘hold down’ global networks
(for overviews see MacLeod 2001a; Scott 1998;
Storper 1997). The other strand, focusing specifically
on inter-firm networks and global commodity/value
chains (GCCs/GVCs), considers the organizational
structures of global firms’ production systems and
explores how particular regions ‘slot into’ these
networks with varying impacts on industrial
upgrading (see Gereffi and Kaplinsky 2001; Gereffi
1994 1996).
In their early formulations, both of these literatures
could be criticized for their failure to effectively
conceptualize regional economic development in
Introduction and theoretical context
One of the many paradoxes of the processes of
‘globalization’ is the continued significance of
‘regions’, in the sense of sub-national spaces as foci
of economic activity. Systemic processes of rapid
technological change, enhanced capital mobility
and neoliberally inspired inter-regional competition
for investment have focused attention on the need
for regional-level interventions among a broad
community of academics and policymakers. Two
recent strands of work attempt to tackle the links
between globalization dynamics and notions of
‘regional development’. One strand places particular
Trans Inst Br Geogr
NS 29 468– 484 2004
ISSN 0020 -2754 © Royal Geographical Society (with The Institute of British Geographers) 2004
975911469.030.png
 
‘Globalizing’ regional development
469
an era of globalization. The new regionalism liter-
ature seemed overly pre-occupied with local trans-
actions and institutional forms at the expense of
the many extra-local connections within which
regions are embedded, while the functional con-
nections between seemingly desirable regional
institutional configurations and actual levels of
economic development were open to question
(Amin and Thrift 1994). The GCC/GVC approaches,
in turn, operated largely at the national scale,
saying little about how particular sub-national
spaces and their institutions are integrated into,
and shaped by, transnational production systems
(for recent critiques, see Henderson
and markets. These relations may be with other
regions within the same national territory, but
increasingly occur at the international scale. Hence,
our conceptualization of a region is not as a tightly
bounded space, but as a porous territorial forma-
tion whose notional boundaries are straddled by a
broad range of network connections (Amin 2002;
Allen
. 1998).
The paper is organized into two main sections.
First, we explore how the strategic coupling of
global production networks and regional assets
may (or may not, depending on the context) facili-
tate the processes of the creation, enhancement and
capture of value upon which regional development
ultimately depends. Second, in order to illustrate
how our conceptual framework might be utilized
empirically, we present an illustrative case study of
the German car manufacturer BMW and its interac-
tions with regional development processes in East-
ern Bavaria, Germany and Rayong, Thailand.
et al
et al
. 2002;
Smith
2001).
Recent developments in these two fields, how-
ever, have begun to address these shortcomings
and to move somewhat closer together. The ‘new
regionalism’ literature, for example, places increased
weight on the extra-local dynamics shaping eco-
nomic growth within regions (both knowledge,
capital and labour flows and also the wider institu-
tional structures within which regions are embedded
(e.g. Amin 2002; MacKinnon
et al
. 2002; Dicken
et al.
‘Globalizing’ regional development:
towards a re-conceptualization
. 2002; Bunnell
and Coe 2001; MacLeod 2001a; Lovering 1999).
Conversely, a number of GCC and GVC studies
explicitly explore how regional clusters and indus-
trial districts are incorporated into global production
systems, and consider their implications for local eco-
nomic development and industrial upgrading (e.g.
Bair and Gereffi 2001; Gereffi
et al
In developing a broad conceptual framework for
understanding regional development we need to
pay analytical attention
to endogenous growth
factors within specific regions
both
also to the
strategic needs of trans-local actors coordinating
global production networks (cf. Scott and Storper
2003). In our framework, regional development is
conceptualized as
and
2001; Humphrey
2001; Sturgeon 2001; Humphrey and Schmitz 2000).
In this paper, we seek to make a primarily
et al.
a dynamic outcome of the complex
interaction between territorialized relational networks
and global production networks within the context of
changing regional governance structures
con-
ceptual
contribution to these converging research
agendas. Drawing upon a global production net-
works (GPN) perspective (see Henderson
. In that sense,
it resonates with Amin’s topological/relational
view (Amin 2002; see also Dicken 2004). We aim
to specify the interactive complementarity and
coupling effects between localized growth factors
and the strategic needs of trans-local actors in
propelling regional development. We argue that it
is these
.
2002), and deriving insights from both the new
regionalist and GCC and GVC literatures, our
approach focuses on the dynamic ‘strategic cou-
pling’ of global production networks and regional
assets, an interface mediated by a range of institu-
tional activities across different geographical and
organizational scales.
et al
that contribute to regional
development, not inherent regional advantages
or rigid configurations of globalization processes.
Despite certain path-dependent trajectories, regional
development remains a highly contingent process
that cannot be predicted
interactive effects
Our contention is that
regional development ultimately will depend on
the ability of this coupling to stimulate processes of
value creation, enhancement and capture.
We regard regional development as a set of
1
rela-
. This conceptual-
ization, however, does not mean that regional
institutions are unimportant. On the contrary.
Often, such complementarity and coupling effects
can be enhanced and exploited through particular
sets and practices of ‘regional’ institutions. The
a priori
tional processes
(see Amin 2002). It is also, by defini-
tion, an
process (Massey 1984). The
fortunes of regions are shaped not only by what is
going on within them, but also through wider sets
of relations of control and dependency, of competition
interdependent
470
Neil M Coe et al.
Figure 1
A framework for analysing regional development and global production networks
term ‘regional’ must be used with care here. We
place it in scare quotes to indicate that, in reality,
regional development is not just shaped by regionally
specific institutions, but also by a variety of extra-
local institutions (e.g. national, supra-national) that
will impact on activities
sufficient, to generate regional growth in an era in
which competition is increasingly global. There is
no doubt that, for development to take place, a
region must benefit from economies of scale and
scope derived from what Storper (1997, 26) terms
the ‘holy trinity’ of technology–organization–
territory. In Figure 1, we use the term ‘regional
assets’ to describe this necessary precondition for
regional development. In general, these assets can
produce two types of economies. First, economies
of
a region. This ‘scaling’
of institutional influence is critical. In short, regional
development at any particular historical moment
requires the
within
co-presence of three inter-
related sets of conditions:
necessary
can be achieved in certain regions through
highly localized concentrations of specific know-
ledge, skills and expertise. This concentration of
technological advantages embodied in and per-
formed by social actors located in specific regions
creates economies of scale in particular technolo-
gies that can be exploited through the agglomeration
of firms that in turn provide employment and
generate economic outputs within similar high
tech industries. Second, economies of
scale
1 the existence of economies of scale and scope
within specific regions;
2 the possibility of localization economies within
global production networks; and
3 the appropriate configurations of ‘regional’
institutions to ‘hold down’ global production
networks and unleash regional potential.
We have summarized these conditions and their
interactions in Figure 1.
can
exist if these regions are able to reap the intangible
benefits of learning and the cooperative atmo-
sphere embedded in these agglomerations. These
are famously known as ‘spillover’ effects. A variety
of different high value-added activities may be
scope
Regional advantages, global production networks
and economies of value.
Our analytical framework starts with the premise
that endogenous factors are necessary, but in-
975911469.031.png 975911469.032.png 975911469.001.png 975911469.002.png 975911469.003.png 975911469.004.png 975911469.005.png 975911469.006.png 975911469.007.png 975911469.008.png 975911469.009.png 975911469.010.png 975911469.011.png 975911469.012.png 975911469.013.png 975911469.014.png 975911469.015.png 975911469.016.png 975911469.017.png 975911469.018.png 975911469.019.png 975911469.020.png 975911469.021.png 975911469.022.png 975911469.023.png 975911469.024.png 975911469.025.png 975911469.026.png 975911469.027.png 975911469.028.png
‘Globalizing’ regional development
471
Table I
Local and non-local dimensions of regional development
Dimensions
Local manifestations
Non-local forms
Firms
Indigenous SMEs
Global corporations
Industrial clusters
Entrepreneurial subsidiaries
Intra-regional markets
Distant global markets
Venture capitalists
Decentralized business and financial networks
Global production networks
Labour
Skilled and unskilled workers
Skilled experts and technologists
Permanent migrants
Transient migrants
Transnational business elites
Technology
Spillover effects
Global standards and practices
Tacit knowledge
Intra-firm R&D activities
Infrastructure and assets
Technological licensing
Strategic alliances
Institutions
Conventions and norms
Labour and trade unions
Growth coalitions
Business associations
Local authorities
National agencies and authorities
Development agencies
Inter-institutional alliances
Supranational and international organizations
located or developed in these regions because the
tendencies towards learning and cooperation
facilitate a broad spectrum of production and
entrepreneurial activities.
We argue that economies of scale and scope
embedded within specific regions are only advan-
tageous to those regions – and bring about regional
development – insofar as such region-specific
economies can complement the
relationships, but also integrate regional and
national economies in ways that have enormous
implications for their developmental outcomes. At
the same time, the precise nature and articulation
of firm-centred production networks are deeply
influenced by the concrete socio-political contexts
within which they are embedded. The process is
especially complex because while the latter are
essentially territorially specific (primarily, though
not exclusively, at the level of the nation-state and/
or the region), the production networks themselves
are not. Global production networks ‘cut through’
national and regional boundaries in highly differ-
entiated ways, influenced in part by regulatory and
non-regulatory barriers and local socio-cultural
conditions, to create structures that are ‘discontinu-
ously territorial’ (see Henderson
of
trans-local actors situated within global production
networks. As shown in Figure 1, when such a com-
plementary effect exists between regions and global
production networks, a coupling process will take
place through which the relational advantages of
regions interact with the strategic needs of actors in
these global production networks. Regional devel-
opment thus depends on such a coupling process
that evolves over time in relation to the rapidly
changing strategic needs of global production
networks and the rather slow transformations in
regional economies of scale and scope. Before we
analyse such a coupling process, it is important to
unpack what we mean by the
strategic needs
et al
. 2002; Dicken
and Malmberg 2001).
Put in these conceptual terms, it becomes clear
that local actors in specific regions (e.g. labour and
the state) and non-local actors in global production
networks (e.g. TNCs and financial capital) are dif-
ferentiated by their degree of
of
actors in global production networks. We define
strategic needs
territorial embedded-
ness
which, in turn, will have very significant
implications for regional development (see Table I).
This distinction in territorial embeddedness is
important because it shapes how value and power
are distributed in their relational interactions, a
point we develop in the next section (see also
Hudson 2001).
As key local actors in regional development, the
organizational strength and flexibility of labour is
global production networks
as the globally organized
nexus of interconnected functions and operations
by firms and non-firm institutions through which
goods and services are produced and distributed.
Such networks not only integrate firms (and parts
of firms) into structures which blur traditional
organizational boundaries through the develop-
ment of diverse forms of equity and non-equity
975911469.029.png
472
Neil M Coe et al.
critical to the alignment of the region with the stra-
tegic needs of focal firms in global production net-
works. While labour has been internationalizing
through inter-institutional alliances and interna-
tional organizations (see Table I), the reality
remains that in most cases labour is spatially
entrapped in local labour markets (see Herod 2001;
Peck 1996). To Castree
have strongly embedded local labour markets,
we argue that focal firms in global production
networks can better exploit economies of scale
through technology- or expertise-specific produc-
tion systems (e.g. in biotechnology or cultural
industries). In regions with more flexible labour
markets, economies of scope might be better
achieved through the co-presence of a variety of
different industries that reap the benefits of
‘untraded interdependencies’. The role of state
institutions is important here through their regula-
tion of labour and its organizations. In some
regions, state institutions may work with labour
organizations and labour market intermediaries to
increase the skill levels of labour and the flexibility
of local labour markets (see Benner 2003; Peck
2000; Jones 1999). In other regions, the adversarial
and confrontational relationship between the state
and labour may significantly reduce the region’s
attractiveness to focal firms in global production
networks (see Kelly 2002).
Before we move on to unravel the complexity
behind the strategic considerations of focal firms in
global production networks, it is useful to consider
one significant category of non-local actors that
impact significantly on local and regional develop-
ment: financial capital institutions. While global
production networks may not directly encapsulate
financial capital in their network configuration, it
is useful to distinguish three types of financial
capital in relation to their differential territorial
embeddedness: local venture capital, national bank-
ing institutions and globally decentralized financial
networks (see Table I). From the perspective of
global production networks, venture capital tends
to be highly localized primarily because talents
and expertise are often embodied in people within
a particular region that are known to venture
capitalists through interpersonal networks of rela-
tionships. Venture capital is important to regional
development both in terms of its financing of high
risk ventures that are more likely to be at the cut-
ting edge of technological development and in
terms of its financing of supporting industries that
supply to global production networks. The nature
and organization of local venture capital, however,
is embedded within national banking systems.
In some countries, venture capital is much less
active because of the close relationships between
banks and industries (e.g. Germany and Japan).
Regional developmental trajectories are highly
dependent on the direction and influence of national
, workers face a particu-
lar kind of geographical dilemma because ‘what
might make sense for them at one geographical
scale may have unfortunate consequences at other
scales’ (2004, 119). They thus recognize that
et al.
it’s not just that workers may be tempted to put local
interests first, it’s also that the very
of local
interests varies depending on the specifics of local
industry, local standards of living, local living wages
and so on. (Castree
nature
et al.
2004, 120; original emphasis)
In short, there is a
case that economies of
scale and scope in particular regions can be reaped
more effectively by focal firms in global production
networks through labour’s spatial immobility
and flexibility in skills. The local and the regional
become the most important geographical scales
through which labour interacts with the strategic
needs of key actors in global production networks.
Their interactive effects tend to favour trans-local
actors embedded in these global production
networks because, as pointed out some time ago by
Massey (1984) among others, these global actors
can engage in ‘spatial switching’ much more easily
than workers themselves.
Similarly, the state and its development agencies
are institutions that are strongly embedded locally
in specific regions (see Table I again). This institu-
tional dimension of regional development has been
well theorized in the new regionalism literature
(e.g. MacLeod 2001b). It is sufficient to say that the
increasing devolution of political and economic
authority from the nation state to local and
regional institutions has led not only to the rise of
growth coalitions within specific regions, but also
to a higher degree of uneven regional develop-
ment. The latter phenomenon occurs primarily
because different regions have very different con-
figurations of state institutions that in turn shape
how these regions are articulated into global pro-
duction networks. This situational power and role
of the state (and labour) and its manifestations in
local and regional institutions has very important
implications for understanding the distributional
aspects of regional development. In regions that
prima facie
Zgłoś jeśli naruszono regulamin